Cash transfer policies, taxation and the fall in inequality in Brazil an integrated microsimulation-CGE analysis
Abstract
Persistent and very high-income inequality is a well-known feature of the Brazilian economy. However, from 2001 to 2014, the Gini index registered an unprecedented fall of 13.5% percent, combined with significant poverty reduction. Previous studies using partial equilibrium analysis have pointed out the important role of federal government transfer programs in this inequality reduction, particularly in the first period (2001–2005) when the new trend started. The aim of this research is to evaluate the efficiency of the two most important cash transfer programs, “Bolsa Família (PBF)” and “Benefício de Prestação Continuada (BPC)”, in achieving their purpose of alleviating poverty and reducing inequality in Brazil’s income distribution. The simulation results, using an integrated modeling approach, confirm the importance of these programs in reducing inequality from 2003 to 2005. However, the effect on poverty alleviation was not strong. Finally, the methodological approach reveals some important mechanisms that were not present in previous analyses, such as the role of the tax structure that finances these policies.
1. Introduction
It is widely known that Brazil has one of the most unequal income distributions in the world, with a Gini index around 0.60 until the beginning of this century.1 This high income inequality has been one of the main causes of the country’s equally high levels of poverty, despite often strong economic growth.
However, from 2001 to 2014, there was an unprecedented and continuous fall in income inequality, with the Gini index declining 13.5% from 0.594 to 0.5132. This has coincided with a significant reduction of poverty. Between 2001 and 2014, the percentage of poor declined from 38.7% to 15.3%, while the percentage of extremely poor declined from 17.4% to 4.6%.3 These evolutions coincided with the introduction and expansion of targeted income transfer programs as part of a national poverty alleviation strategy.
There are many kinds of income transfer programs in Brazil, such as Programa Bolsa Família (PBF), Benefício de Prestação Continuada (BPC)4 and several retirement benefits and pensions. This research analyzes the first two programs (PBF and BPC) because they are the main cash transfer programs specifically designed as social policies with the purpose of poverty (and inequality) reduction.
PBF was created in October 2003 and is presently the federal government’s main cash transfer program. It is a cash transfer program with conditions such as 85% school attendance for children in schooling age, vaccination for children under six years old, and regular visits to a health center for both pregnant and breastfeeding women. In 2005, PBF had a total of 10.6 million beneficiary households and R$6.9 billion worth of transfers (equivalent to 0.3% of GDP in 2005).
BPC is a social assistance benefit since 1996. It aims to aid the elderly who are not included in the public social security system and the disabled who cannot support themselves despite their households’ financial care. Both beneficiary groups comprise 2.8 million beneficiaries, with a budget of R$9.7 billion (or 0.4% of GDP) for BPC in 2005. The benefit consists of a cash transfer amounting to one minimum wage (R$300 in 2005) where the beneficiary’s family per capita income must be less than a quarter of the minimum wage.
These programs aim to reduce poverty and income inequality, hence the need for evaluations of their effects. The most common approach is partial equilibrium and decomposition analysis. Hoffmann (2006b) points out that 31% of the decline in Brazil’s inequality – 87% in the country’s Northeast region – from 2002 to 2004 were due to the above mentioned programs. Barros et al. (2007c) estimated that PBF and BPC induced, respectively, around 11.8% and 11.1% of the fall in income inequality from 2001 to 2005. According to IPEA (2012), during the period from 2001 to 2011, these two programs contributed to reduce inequality by 17% (and up to 24% between 2003 and 2005).
The contribution of PBF and BPC is more impressive if one takes into account the limited budget of these public policies. In 2013, the total budget of the public social security system represented 10.9% of GDP (6.8% for the general system – INSS, and 4.1% for former public workers) while PBF and BPC represented only 0.5% and 0.65%, approximately.5
However, these partial equilibrium or decomposition approaches do not take into account systemic (general equilibrium) effects induced by these programs on the economy, as well as the feedback impacts to household income and consumer prices. When poor households receive transfers, they tend to consume more, which stimulates production and employment, and so on through a multiplier effect. These demand effects are enhanced when we take into account differences in the expenditure patterns of Brazilian households by income level. Among poor urban Brazilian households, food expenditure is 40% of total consumption, compared to only 12% for the richest households (Cury et al., 2006).
In addition, the relevance of the general equilibrium effects is justified by the size and evolution of the transfer programs. Almost 14 million households (around 20% of all households) are PBF beneficiaries, covering more than 50 million individuals (around 25% of the population). In 2014, the total value of cash transfers was R$27.2 billion, representing more than 0.5% of the Brazilian GDP.
In addition, we may expect that program effects are sensitive to the mechanism chosen to finance this specific public expenditure, which generate direct and general equilibrium effects of their own. Also, during 2003–2005 some important changes were introduced in the fiscal system. For example, in the social security budget, the sharpest revenue increase came from PIS-COFINS taxes (a rise of 30% in their GDP ratio), which in 2003–2004 started to levy imports.
Additionally, cash transfers may cause some beneficiaries to reduce labor supply. This may counteract some of the benefits of these programs. Recently, several studies aimed to estimate the effects of the PBF and other conditional cash transfer programs on adult labor supply in Brazil (e.g., Soares et al., 2007; Ferro and Nicollela, 2007; Teixeira, 2008; Covre et al., 2008; and Foguel and Barros, 2008). These studies use different empirical strategies to compare beneficiaries against comparable non-beneficiaries.
There is some evidence that PBF can reduce labor market participation mainly among beneficiary mothers. For example, Tavares (2008) found evidence of an adverse effect of PBF on beneficiary mothers’ willingness to participate in the labor market due, mainly, to the program’s conditionalities (education and health of children). On the other hand, Firpo et al. (2014) find evidence that some individuals (particularly women) deliberately reduce their labor income in order to qualify for the PBF. Similarly, Santos (2013) shows that the PBF has encouraged adult beneficiaries to offer informal labor. In both cases, the purpose of the beneficiary is hiding the real family income to continue receiving the cash grant.
Proving that a specific methodology is unequivocally superior to others is not an easy task. However, according to Cockburn et al. (2015), the analysis of the impacts of large-scale policies on income distribution requires the usage of tool that integrates microsimulation (MS) techniques and a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model. Given the systemic consequences of the PBF and BPC programs and their financing mechanisms on the overall economy, we adopt a CGE model integrated with a Microsimulation model (CGE-MS model) approach to evaluate the impacts of these programs on poverty and inequality in Brazil.
This paper is organized into five sections, including this introduction. The next section describes the methodology: the CGE model, the MS model, and their integration. The research questions, simulation scenarios and results are presented in Section 3. The last section presents the conclusion and the final remarks.6
2. Methodology
This study applies a CGE-MS combined iterative approach, where the starting model (i.e. where the first shock is applied) is the MS model. For this reason, this kind of approach is referred to as bottom-up/top-down in the literature (see Cockburn et al., 2015, for a discussion of the various CGE-MS approaches).
2.1 The CGE model
This section briefly describes some key characteristics of the CGE model. Further details on this model can be found in Cury et al. (2010, Appendix A.2).7 The CGE model distinguishes 42 domestic sectors, 8 household types,8 the Government, and the external sector. The model assumes that the Brazilian economy is an international price taker but that the changes of its export prices can affect the external demand for Brazilian goods through an export demand equation. Production is a function of 7 types of labor,9 capital and intermediate inputs and sold as imperfect substitutes in the domestic and international markets.10 Households and firms demand domestic and imported goods according to the Armington (1969) hypothesis.
In terms of closure, the nominal exchange rate is exogenous, while the price index is endogenous. Foreign savings is also exogenous, which implies a fixed balance of trade. Government spending is fixed exogenously, but the total public deficit is endogenous. Investment is determined by total savings where the marginal propensity to save is fixed.
2.2 The microsimulation model (MS)
The database for the microsimulations is the National Survey by Household Sampling 2003 (PNAD 2003). It contains a nationally representative sample of almost 384,834 individuals distributed in 117,010 households.11 As it does not contain information about household expenditures, the MS model focuses on individual labor supply.
Each working-age individual (over 10 years old) was classified according to the seven labor categories in the CGE model. Formal and informal workers are assumed to have flexible wage. However, as public servants in Brazil benefit from a job stability clause, it is assumed that their employment levels are fixed.12 The sample includes 106,590 working-age individuals, representing 48,742,853 individuals in the total population.
The MS model is based on Savard (2003). The main adaptation for this model is the use of a segmented labor market.13 For the unemployed, the reservation wage of each individual determines the choice to supply (or not) labor in the market.
One of the main difficulties in making CGE-MS integration work is convergence. For this convergence to be successful the two databases must have the same values. Thus, the individual weights were multiplied by a factor (reweighting) so that the PNAD 2003 database reflects the CGE model data. Table 1 presents the results of this reweighting for employed and unemployed people.
A prior concern regarding the individuals’ reservation wage estimation is the issue related to labor supply identification. In principle, the expansion of income transfers exogenously affects the willingness to supply labor of various demographic groups in different ways. Thus, it is necessary to estimate an equation for individual labor supply, identified by the number of individual work hours, as a function of the individual wage-hour after changes in income transfers for each demographic group has been considered. It is also necessary to correct the potential auto-selection bias to labor supply participation. After applying this procedure, it is possible to properly identify the different reactions of the labor supply to exogenous changes in the size of transfers for individuals in each demographic group. Therefore, the estimation procedure can be described in two steps as follows:
Step 1
At this microsimulation stage, we are interested in the individual impact due an income transfers shock, especially for the demographic group of single mothers who are heads of household. This demographic group is the main beneficiary of the PBF and deserves special attention because it is the most sensitive to non-labor income from transfer programs, as found in our MS model results.
Our empirical strategy is based on a simpler version in which the worker makes an individual decision. Due to the identification problem of the non-linear budget constraint, we estimated a reduced-form hour equation as a function of the individual’s wage, the income from transfers programs, other income, and a number of demographic controls. The “other income” variable combines all sources of non-labor income, following Blundell and McCurdy (1999). This last variable for married women, for example, is calculated by taking the husband’s actual earnings into account. On the other hand, we created another variable that represents the BPC and PBF programs in order to capture the effects of the income transfers on labor supply.14
The predicted working hours are obtained from the observed and non-observed individual and household characteristics and his own wage. Therefore, the worker i’s predicted hours of work
where αi, θi, βi, δi and γi are the parameters to be estimated; wi is the hourly wage rate for individual i ; Qi is the vector of the total household income net of the earnings (including income transfers) received by the individual i ; Bi is the vector of benefits received (PBF and BPC) by individual i in 2003; Zi represents the individuals’ observable characteristics; ui is the random error term, which captures the non-observable characteristics that affect the individual labor supply; and j is the individual’s demographic group, 1 being for men, 2 for woman head of household with children, and 3 for other women (who are not heads of households). The value of θ determines the substitution effect related to sensitivity of individual labor supply to changes in wages. The values of β and δ represent the income effect, that is, the impact of non-labor income on labor supply.
The Zi vector of individual characteristics was composed of the following variables:
where educ denotes the number of years of schooling, age is a proxy to the level of experience; famsize is the family size in terms of number of individuals (excluding pensioners, domestic servants and their parents), Da is a dummy for the area where the family’s domicile is located (0 for urban and 1 for rural).
Individual working hours are observed only for those who are already employed. Thus, the sample of individuals that present strictly positive work hours is not random. However, it is possible that the choice to work is related to income-dependent variables, either from labor or non-labor (other income sources). Therefore, the situation is typically one of endogenous selection, in which there is a decision to participate or not in the labor market and, given that the individual had decided to work, it is necessary to determine how many working hours he will offer. In order to control for potential selection bias, the procedure proposed by Heckman (1979) is applied, which consists of:
where Φ is a function of accumulated distribution, where Si is a qualitative variable representing the occupational choice for an individual i: this variable will take the value 0, if the individual does not supply work, or 1, if otherwise. The variable γi is a vector of estimated parameters that determine the probability that the individual takes part in the labor market. Yi is the vector representing the variables related to labor and non-labor incomes that affect the decision to supply labor by individual i. As before, Zi are the individual characteristics that determine the probability of participating in the labor market.
The equations (1) and (3) are estimated by a two-stage method proposed by Heckman (1979). In this model, equation (3) corrects sample selection bias by non-observables. The selection variables used for identification are educ, age, age2 and famsize. To test and correct the sample selection bias we estimate a probit model of labor market participation with these selection variables. These equations are run separately for three demographic groups: men, female household heads with children, and other women, to estimate the elasticity of labor supply. The inverse of Mills’ ratio λ(zγ) is extracted from equation (3), which is applied to equation (1) to ensure that the parameters of these equations are consistently estimated.
After estimating the coefficients in (1) and the inverse of Mills’ ratio, it is possible to estimate the adjusted working hours of each individual,
Step 2
The second part of the microsimulation process is the computation of the reservation wages and the new employment ratio. Individual labor supply is a function of individual market wage rates and non-labor income, among other variables. These wage rates can be observed for wage workers. For others there is an unobservable wage rate that an individual could potentially receive.
According to Heckman (1974) it is possible to express this reservation wage as a function of their individual characteristics as well as non-labor income and other constraints.
Following Savard (2003), the non-observed reservation wage is obtained from the observable and non-observable individual’s characteristics, as well as household characteristics. Due to the importance of evaluating the reservation wage before and after an income transfer shock, we include non-labor income in the structural reservation wage equation and identify the income transfer variable separately. Therefore, the worker i ‘ s reservation log wage,
where αi, βi, δi and γi are the parameters to be estimated. The observed wage,
Due to the impossibility of observing the wage offer to the sample’s unemployed individuals, we need to estimate a probit model that determines the probability of these individual taking part in the labor market. This probability,Si = 1, is estimated by the function:
where: Φ is a function of accumulated distribution; γi is a vector of estimated parameters that determine the probability of the individual taking part in the labor market; as before, Zi and Yi are, respectively, the individual characteristics and the work and non-work income that determine the probability of participating in the labor market; and Dg is a demographic dummy (0 for man, 1 for female household heads with children, 2 for other women).
As for equations (1) and (3), equations (4) and (5) are estimated by the Heckman two-stage method. This makes it possible to calculate the reservation wage of each individual,
If the estimated reservation wage
After making this comparison for each employed person, the model determines the Heckman pre-simulation occupational level by private labor type (HLsl) by summing up the number of people originally unemployed with the number of people that would be unemployed according to the Heckman criterion. It deserves mentioning that this occupational level is different from the original level in the database (Lsl), given that there are people in the database that work and earn wages lower than their estimated reservation wages. This occurs because the latter wages are estimates of what these people could earn in the market according to their individual and household characteristics. Therefore, merely applying the Heckman procedure to the database changes the occupational level for each labor type.
As proposed by Savard (2003), the selection of individuals who should be unemployed starts with classifying workers according to their reservation wages. Those with the highest reservation wage will be the first to become unemployed if the real wage decreases. If there is a positive change in the real wages, the first to be employed will be those with the lowest reservation wage.18
Step 3
In this section we evaluate the relationship between the conditional cash transfer programs and individual work decisions through substitution and income effects. In Table 2 we present the marginal effects in respect to hours of work, implied by the estimates from steps 1 and 2.
The wage compensated elasticity of labor supply reflects the strength of the substitution effect from the perspective of labor income. The wage elasticities are the coefficients reported by the variable log w in equation (1). For women without children (j = 3) this elasticity is positive and higher than for women who are household heads (j = 2), which is to be expected according to the results of many empirical studies. For men, the negative elasticity is not usual, but it is statistically non-significant.
The magnitude of the income effect is reflected by the income elasticity of labor supply. These income elasticities – described by the variables log B (public transfer benefits) and log Q (all other non-labor income) in equation (1) – are all negative, as expected. The highest sensibility is related to the group formed by female household heads with children, which is in line with the great majority of empirical work on this subject. Also, the results are consistent with standard theory and show that cash benefits may have participation effects on specific population groups.
2.3 Integration of the CGE and MS models
The impacts of the PBF and BPC programs on welfare indicators are assessed with an integrated CGE-MS modeling framework with a bi-directional linkage to guarantee convergence of solutions for both models. The following illustrates how this bi-directional procedure:
Step 1
The MS model contains data on thousands of individuals, estimates the reservation wage
First, for each simulation, the benefits received from the income transfer programs in 2003 (Bi) are replaced by their new values
Step 2
The occupational levels compatible with the new values of benefits
and
The new values of taxes used to finance the changes in transfer programs (B*) are also applied to the CGE model to simulate the changes they induce in the economic environment.
All these changes induce the economic system to achieve a new general equilibrium and, as part of this process, the labor market reach equilibrium with new real wage values
Step 3
The percentage change in the average real wage
After classifying the workers by their reservation wages, those with the highest reservation wage are the first to become unemployed if the real wage decreases. However, if the real wage rises, the first to be employed will be those with the lowest reservation wage. Adding the number of people to be employed or unemployed according to this criterion to the initial occupational level defines a new occupational level for each private labor type
Step 4
These new occupational levels are then transmitted to the CGE model as shown in Figure 1:
If the occupational levels calculated by the MS model are different from those in the CGE model, they change the equilibrium of the labor markets, which will then change wages and the economic environment as a whole until the CGE model reaches a new equilibrium. In this sense, step 2 restarts, but without changes in benefits and their financing sources, and this integrated solution procedure loops until the differences in the occupational level for all private labor types calculated by the MS model (Lsl*) approaches zero.21
This association is done consistently with the equilibrium of aggregate markets in the CGE model, which requires that: (i) relative changes in average earnings in the MS model must be equal to changes in wage rates from the CGE model for each private wage group in the labor market; (ii) relative changes in the number of privately waged workers by labor market segment in the MS model must match those in the CGE model; and (iii) changes in the consumption price vector, p, must be consistent with the CGE.22
According to the above procedure, the private labor supply is being modified with each simulation iteration; for example, some individuals will be losing their former jobs. If this happens, the share of each household in the total income of each labor category can also change (parameter εhl in equation 2.1.2). In order to capture these variations, we incorporate the differences among the parameter εhl, along the simulation rounds as a shock in the CGE as well, which performs simultaneously with the procedures described in this section.23
2.4 Non-labor income procedures
After the CGE and MS models’ solutions converge, it is still necessary to treat non-labor incomes before calculating poverty and inequality indicators. Basically, the variables related to these sources of income in the MS model follow the CGE variations or maintain the same value as in the household survey, as shown in Table 3. In the former case, the changes from the CGE model are transmitted to the corresponding variables in the MS model in a unidirectional way.
3. Simulations and results
3.1 Description of simulations
The direct aiming of the simulations is to assess the effects of changing values and beneficiaries of the programs PBF and BPC from the ones presented in 2003 to the ones presented in 2005.
Transfer programs
We addressed the changes between 2003 and 2005 with similar procedures adopted by Barros et al. (2007c).27 However, we construct a specific imputation methodology for the 2005 additional benefits.28 Given this information, we then took the benefit share for the eight CGE household categories and apply the actual amounts given by Brazil’s budget data, ensuring consistency with our SAM data. The values are shown in Table 4.
The table above shows the differences in benefits between 2005 and 2003. Total transfers increased by R$6,392 million, which represents 0.57% of total household income. By program, the increase was approximately 116% for BF and 53% for BPC. Also, there was an overall improvement in the targeted group. The poorest households in the CGE model (F1, F2 and F3) increase their total BF share from 44.9% (2003) to 46.1% (2005). However, despite some improvements, the data show that the BPC targeting was much worse than the BF program (19.4% in 2003 and 26.6% in 2005).
We carried out two simulations, distinguished by whether the increased transfers are financed by public deficit (which reduces total savings and investment, according to the model’s macro closure) or increased taxes: SIMU A and SIMU B.
SIMU B
In this simulation, the increase in benefits is financed by increased federal government taxes. This choice was made in order to hold the nominal public deficit almost constant. The main justification for this policy arrangement is the “Brazilian Fiscal Responsibility Law”, which states that new expenditures must be explicitly financed.
In order to replicate what happened in that period, we did an extensive analysis of the 2005 federal budget data to identify the specific tax sources that financed the PBF-BPC programs during that year. Table 5 summarizes the amounts of each federal tax source, their percentage composition, and the equivalent CGE tax as presented in the CGE model.
From this table,29 we collected the share of each tax in the total increase of program expenditure (R$6,392,065,000). Thus, the following adjustments were made to the CGE model: (i) 2.2% increase in direct taxes on the gross income of the eight CGE household categories and firms; (ii) introduction of the Cofins tax through the replication of the PIS-COFINS tax reform, which was implemented by the federal government in the same period. From the total revenue generated by this reform, 27.5% was appropriated as funding for the cash transfer programs.
3.2 Macroeconomic impacts
Table 6 presents selected macro results for SIMU A and SIMU B. We first analyze SIMU B, which captures the combined effects of changes in transfers and taxes, while the results from SIMU A capture only the impacts of changes in transfers (and the public deficit).
In general, the macro impacts are adverse since they induce a real GDP fall of 0.46% and an aggregate employment decrease of 0.48%, while generating a price index increase of 0.65%. These adverse effects can mainly be attributed to the partial reform of PIS-COFINS that were the main tax sources of the transfer programs.
PIS-COFINS reform increases the taxation of firms’ value-added (VA), which leads to either higher marginal revenues or lower marginal costs through the reduction of VA components. Since capital is fixed by sector, this implies a lower labor demand, which induces a decrease in wages and, ultimately, household income. Specifically, the fall in aggregate consumption is due to the decrease in overall household income despite the rise of income among the poorest households who benefit most from the increase in transfers.
The taxation of imports increases their prices in the domestic market and induces another adverse effect on aggregate consumption, through higher domestic prices.
Exports fall due to the price-responsive behavior of external agents and the model’s external closure characteristics. First, the simulation induces an increase in domestic prices, which causes a decrease in external demand for Brazilian export goods. Second, since external macro closure implies a constant trade balance, the fall in imports must be accompanied by a fall in exports.
The government deficit increases by 7.88%, which shows that the ex-ante simulated taxation was not enough to completely finance the total transfer costs. Despite the “total financing” intention of SIMU B, the government deficit was not held constant because the taxes dead weight losses turn out to be very strong during the simulation.30
The comparison between SIMU A and SIMU B demonstrates the isolated effects of transfers without the tax increases. GDP in SIMU A is practically stable. However, the shock induces a trade-off between consumption and investment, with the former increasing by 0.5% and the latter decreasing by 1.42%. This fact can be explained by the increase in income transfer and by the higher public deficit (+17.89%), which reduces total savings. The consequent fall in investment will reduce economic growth in the near future, engendering additional negative effects not captured in this analysis. Therefore we can conclude that the adverse impacts of SIMU B are due to the simulated program’s financing structure.
3.3 Impacts on labor market
SIMU B has an adverse effect on aggregate employment (−0.48%, according to Table 6). In SIMU A, the effect is small (−0.11%) but it is one of the few macro aggregates with negative impacts.
Table 7 shows that employment falls for all categories of workers in the private sector. The number of public worker does not change because, by model assumption and legal status, the quantities are fixed and the adjustments are done through flexible real wages.
In the SIMU B, among the private sector, we can see two patterns. The effects are more pronounced in the informal markets (L1 and L2) and among less skilled workers.
In our interpretation, with lower imports and a fixed trade balance, there is pressure to overvalue the real exchange rate making exports more expensive. The sectors in which exports are more sensitive to price changes are the most traditional ones, which are more intensive in informal and low-skilled workers. On the other hand, the fall of consumption in high income households affect the employment of more skilled workers in the sectors that produce goods with higher technological content, such as automobiles, auto parts, electronic, electrical, and pharmaceutical industries.
Table 8 show generally negative impacts on real wages by labor type. In the SIMU B, the wage of less skilled workers (L1 and L3) fall more than the other types. The reduction in public servants’ earnings is due to the model hypothesis stressed above.
Table 9 shows the effects on the total labor income, combining wage and employment effects. These are stronger among the less skilled workers, especially for those in the informal market, and due mainly to real wage effects.
Again, SIMU A has practically no significant adverse effects. In contrast to SIMU B, informal unskilled workers (L1) fare better, due to the fact that there is a reallocation of production toward more labor-intensive sectors.
Finally, it is important to stress that the convergence procedures affect the final labor market equilibrium. Table 10 illustrates this process for SIMU B. The first line show changes in real wages, the price index and GDP in the first simulation round. In the second line, the same variables are presented for the last round. The convergence solution shows that changes in the transfer programs induce general equilibrium effects that initially affect wages primarily and then, due to the iterative process, are partially reallocated to employment impacts (quantity effects).
3.4 Impacts on income distribution
Table 11 shows the impacts of the changes in the transfer programs on inequality indicators. In general, the results confirm the important role of transfer programs in the fall in Brazil’s inequality during that period.31.
Analyzing the Gini index, the fall of –0.48% (SIMU B) is slightly lower than the ones reported by other studies that evaluated the contribution of transfer programs to the fall in inequality using partial equilibrium or decomposition analysis. Barros et al. (2007c) found that 22.9% of the total Gini decrease between 2001 and 2005 was due to BF and BPC. In the same period, these authors reported a total decrease in the Gini index of –2.6%. Therefore, the decrease displayed in Table 10 accounts for approximately 14% (SIMU A) and 19% (SIMU B) of the total fall in inequality during that period.
Here, it is important to stress some differences between our simulations and the study by Barros et al. (2007c). The simulations capture the effects of changes in a shorter period, from 2003 to 2005, in a general equilibrium environment. Although the period is different, we found evidence that the transfer programs alone (SIMU A) had lower effects on inequality than those reported by other studies. However, in the case of SIMU B, the effect is similar.
Table 12 shows the impacts on household income. The changes in programs have a slightly adverse effect on national average household income in SIMU A (−0.18 %), which is magnified (−0.81%) in SIMU B. In both, the positive effects on the three poorest household categories are primarily due to the increase in transfer amounts to them. On the other hand, the effects of the programs’ expansion on the richest households (F7 and F8) are already negative in the first simulation (SIMU A) and are magnified when the changes in taxation were considered. There are two important causes of these negative impacts. The first is related to labor income reported in the former section. The other can be attributed to the general price increase and its effect on non-labor income such as social security benefits and interest on fixed income investments.
The positive impacts of the program’s expansion on the poorest household category are better reflected by SIMU A. This simulation also captures systemic effects induced from these programs, as shown in Sections 3.2 and 3.4. Besides that, SIMU B also shows the additional negative impact of the increase of taxation. This helps to understand the improvement of the Gini index in SIMU B in relation to the SIMU A. Aside from capturing the income increase of the poorest households, it also captures the fall in income of the richest households due to the increased taxation.
3.5 Impacts on poverty
The effects on poverty are presented in Table 13. Based on observed and simulated income per household head, we calculate three poverty indicators: Headcount index (P0), Poverty Gap (P1) and Severity of Poverty (P2). These indicators are calculated using the microsimulation model before and after simulations. The reference line values are from September 2005 estimated by Barros et al. (2007b) and deflated to 2003 with the IPCA (Índice de Preços ao Consumidor Amplo) price index.
The general reduction in poverty indicators (P0, P1 and P2) shows that the transfer programs alone (SIMU A) had positive effects on poverty and on extreme poverty. From the results in the Table 13 we also see that the impacts on poverty were reduced by the changes in taxation (SIMU B). As discussed above, tax changes generate some adverse impacts that affect the poor population and, in a more intensive way, the extremely poor individuals. As we have seen previously in Section 3.4, the impacts on labor income were stronger among the less skilled workers (L1 and L3) and the informal workers (L1 and L2). These workers are predominantly from the poorest households, which are highly dependent on labor income. Therefore, despite the increase in the received benefits, some households fall into poverty due to increased taxation.
In the case of SIMU B, the program expansion did not have an impact on extreme poverty. However, the poverty gap and severity of extreme poverty worsened. One explanation is the deterioration of non-labor income due to the price increase, which especially affected the family F2 located, before shock, just above the poverty line and whose income is basically derived from social security benefits.
4. Conclusions
The aim of the simulations presented here was to investigate the role of the two most important Brazilian cash transfer programs in reducing inequality. This was done through a CGE-microsimulation (CGE-MS) iterative approach. Two simulations were run, where the cost of increased transfers was financed by increased taxes or a rise in the public deficit.
The macro results showed that, in general, the impacts were adverse for several macro indicators, including GDP, employment, and price index. However, importantly, the study’s CGE-MS framework brings out the fact that the adverse results came mainly from the tax increases and not the increase in transfers.
The results confirmed the important role of the PBF and BPC programs in the recent reduction in income inequality in Brazil. Practically 20% of the fall in inequality between 2003 and 2005 can be attributed to the adopted policies. These results are similar to those reported by other studies using partial equilibrium/decomposition analysis. However, again, this study’s CGE-MS framework reveals that the accompanying tax reform played a major role in this process.
The programs also contributed to a reduction in poverty. However, the impacts were smaller than for inequality. The transfers generated positive impacts, but the general equilibrium effects of the changes in taxation to finance the program largely offset the former effect, particularly in the case of extreme poverty indicators. Household income was effected through reduction in labor and non-labor income.
In general, the results also demonstrated that the two analyzed programs have achieved their objective of reducing poverty and inequality. However, the simulations showed that PBF targeted its beneficiaries better, concentrating its benefits on poor households.
Finally, it is clear that the financing of transfer programs plays an important role in the final welfare impacts. In our opinion, this issue deserves more attention in a policy research agenda.
Footnotes
1.
See Barros et al. (2007a) and Hoffmann (2006a) for more details.
2.
Recently, starting in 2014, Brazil experienced a severe macroeconomic crisis with GDP falling sharply. Probably, this situation will result in a worsening of social indicators such as the poverty level.
3.
These data were kindly provided by Samuel Franco from OPE Sociais (https://www.opesociais.com.br) and Ricardo Paes de Barros from INSPER, based on the National Survey by Household Sampling (PNAD) from 2001 to 2014.
4.
Henceforth they will be respectively referred as PBF and BPC. The full description and data for these programs are presented in Cury et al. (2010, Appendix D).
5.
6.
Cury et al. (2010, Appendixes A, B, C and D) supplement this article with the equations used in the CGE model, intermediate results, and data on the transfer programs.
7.
The CGE model used in this research is an extension of the one presented by Cury et al. (2005), where further details can be found, and is a result of a series of developments made in the model proposed by Devarajan et al. (1991), as can be seen in Cury (1998), Barros et al. (2000) and Coelho et al. (2003).
8.
Poor urban families headed by an active individual (F1), poor urban families headed by a non-active individual (F2), poor rural families (F3), urban families with low average income (F4), urban families with medium income (F5), rural families with medium income (F6), families with high average income (F7), and families with high income and a significant share of non-wage income (F8).
9.
Unskilled informal (L1), skilled informal (L2), low-skilled formal (L3), average-skilled formal (L4), high-skilled formal (L5), low-skilled public servants (L6) high-skilled public servants (L7).
10.
The SAM used in this research is fully described and documented by Cury et al. (2006), which can be requested from the authors.
11.
See Appendix B in Cury et al. (2010) for database details.
12.
The Brazilian labor market also has a segment of non-flexible wages. However, this segment is formed primarily by public sector workers with job stability clauses. These workers who belong to the factors L6 and L7 are not included in the MS model, but they are agents on CGE model.
13.
In Savard (2003), the labor market is segmented in two types: one with a fixed wage and another one with a flexible wage. Therefore, an individual could alter across three states (observing the implicit costs of choosing each one of them): offering her workforce in each one of the two markets or getting unemployed by choice.
14.
We do not use a household labor supply model that is based on a family joint decision due to various difficulties in identifying the domestic production function (Becker, 1965) from the PNAD data. In this case, we followed the recommendation of Gronau (1986) where the lack of domestic production data should be replaced by family characteristics (such as all types of income) and demographic aspects.
15.
This functional form was proposed because it is consistent with 1) the existence of individuals’ preferences by labor and leisure, and 2) the presence of households’ budget constraints (Blundell and McCurdy, 1999).
16.
The first part of the microsimulation process is the computation of the labor supply equation (1). The entire PNAD sample was considered for this phase. Table B.3 in Cury et al. (2010) contains the overall heckit estimates by the system equation, including the coefficients and their standard errors to 5 percent of significance, as well as the inverse of the Mills’s ratio.
17.
18.
For this phase, only private sector workers are considered. Table B.4 in Cury et al. (2010) contains the econometric estimates of this system of equations and the benefits shocks, changing the log Bi that corresponds to the PBF and BPC amounts of 2003, to log B*I, which corresponds to the benefits amounts of 2005.The procedure to impute these values in the 2003 database is described in Appendix C
19.
This is done in order to capture the changes in the occupational level by private labor type due only to the variation in the benefits, isolated from the effects of applying the Heckman procedure to the database.
20.
For example, if the post-simulation average real wage of high skilled formal workers is 5 percent higher than its initial value in the CGE model, then all wages earned by these workers in the MS model are raised by 5%.
21.
In general, the convergent solutions were obtained in the seventh iteration between the models.
22.
The change in consumption prices is transmitted from the CGE model to the MS model through the variations in the real wages by private worker type, which is used as linking aggregate variables between the models.
23.
Specifically for the simulations carried out, this share parameter did not present significant differences between the simulation rounds. Their changes were so small that they became visible only to the 4th decimal point. This fact implies that, practically, there was no variation of the shares between simulations.
24.
Vector included in the matrix (shk * YK) in equation (3.1.2).
25.
Another vector of matrix (shk * YK) plus government transfers in equation 3.1.2.
26.
Weighted average of the commodities price changes, whose weights are the shares of the respective commodity expenses in the total consumption expenditure of that household.
27.
For 2003, at the micro data level, we used the same adapted household survey, which was provided by the authors.
27.
This is fully explained in Cury et al. (2010, Appendix C).
29.
The total value in Table 5 (R$14,710,000) is equivalent to the sum of 2005 PBF and BPC columns in Table 4. Briefly, the COFINS tax applies to revenue, value-added, and imports. The CPMF tax was collected on all banking transactions (revoked in 2008). The CSLL applies to net profits (after income tax). More detailed data on the programs’ tax sources are presented in Cury et al. (2010, Appendix D).
30.
We suppose that the government was acting ex-ante and was appropriating only the resources required to cover the direct costs of the program. It is reasonable to suppose that the government (ex ante) did not estimate the probable tax losses.
31.
Barros et al (2007d) have several chapters aligned with this view.
References
-
1
Income distribution policy in developing country: A case study of KoreaStanford CA: Stanford University Press.
-
2
mimeoIMMPA: A Quantitative Macroeconomic Framework for the Analysis of Poverty Reduction Strategies, Washington, D.C., The World Bank, mimeo.
-
3
‘A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production’. IMF Staff Papers157–178, ‘A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production’. IMF Staff Papers, 16.
-
4
Desigualdade de Renda no Brasil: uma análise da queda recenteA Queda Recente da Desigualdade de Renda no Brasil, Desigualdade de Renda no Brasil: uma análise da queda recente, Brasília, Ipea, 1.
-
5
Desigualdade de Renda no Brasil: uma análise da queda recenteA importância da queda recente da desigualdade para a Pobreza, Desigualdade de Renda no Brasil: uma análise da queda recente, Brasília, Ipea, 1.
-
6
Desigualdade de Renda no Brasil: uma análise da queda recenteO papel das transferências públicas na queda recente da desigualdade de renda brasileira, Desigualdade de Renda no Brasil: uma análise da queda recente, Brasília, Ipea, 2.
-
7
Pesquisa e Planejamento Econômico157–182, Salário mínimo e pobreza: uma abordagem de equilíbrio geral, Pesquisa e Planejamento Econômico, Rio de Janeiro, IPEA, 30, 2.
- 8
- 9
- 10
- 11
-
12
A labour supply: a review of alternative approachesIn: O Ashenfelter, D Card, editors. Handbook of Labor Economics III. Amsterdam: North Holland. pp. 1559–1695.
-
13
Un modèle CGE-Multi-Ménages Intégrés Appliqué à l’Économie Sénégalaisemimeo: CREA, Dakar.
-
14
Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysis: Challenges and InnovationsPublic pensions in a dynamic microanalytic framework: the case of France, Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysis: Challenges and Innovations, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
-
15
‘Representative versus Real Households in the Macroeconomic Modeling of Inequality’. Working Paper‘Representative versus Real Households in the Macroeconomic Modeling of Inequality’. Working Paper, nº. 2003-05, DELTA/ENS, Paris.
-
16
The Impact of Macroeconomic Policies on Poverty and Income Distribution: Macro-Micro Evaluation Techniques and ToolsA CGE Integrated Multi-Household Model with Segmented Labour Markets and unemployment, The Impact of Macroeconomic Policies on Poverty and Income Distribution: Macro-Micro Evaluation Techniques and Tools, Palgrave-Macmillan Publishers Limited, Houndmills, England.
-
17
‘Welfare impacts of China’s accession to the world trade organization’The World Bank Economic Review 18:29–57.
-
18
‘Poverty-Reduction Targeting Programs: a General Equilibrium Approach’Journal of African Economies 3:309–338.
-
19
Evaluating Targeted Cash Transfer Programs – A General Equilibrium Framework with an Application to Mexico. Research Report 137Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.
-
20
‘Trade liberalization and Poverty in Nepal: A Computable General Equilibrium micro-simulation Analysis’. Working paper‘Trade liberalization and Poverty in Nepal: A Computable General Equilibrium micro-simulation Analysis’. Working paper, nº. 01-18, CREFA, Université Laval.
-
21
The Handbook of Microsimulation ModellingMacro-Micro Models, The Handbook of Microsimulation Modelling, Emerald Group Publishing Limited.
-
22
Um modelo de equilíbrio geral computável para analisar aspectos distributivos no BrasilIn: CH Corseuil, H Kume, editors. A Abertura Comercial Brasileira nos anos 90 – impactos sobre emprego e salário. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA. pp. 171–197.
-
23
‘Poverty and Policy: Some experiments with a SAM-Based CGE Model for Ghana’Paper presented to the XIII International Conference on Input-Output Techniques.
- 24
-
25
PhD dissertation (Doutorado em Economia de Empresas) – Depto de Economia, Escola de Administração de Empresas de São PauloModelo de equilíbrio geral para simulação de políticas de distribuição de renda e crescimento no Brasil, PhD dissertation (Doutorado em Economia de Empresas) – Depto de Economia, Escola de Administração de Empresas de São Paulo, Fundação Getulio Vargas.
-
26
‘From revenue to value added taxes: welfare and fiscal efficiency effects in Brazil’Proceedings of the International Conference on Policy Modeling (ECOMOD 2006).
-
27
mimeoMatriz de Contabilidade Social - Brasil 2003, Relatório de Pesquisa 461/04 (Anexo 1), São Paulo, GV Pesquisa, EAESP–FGV, fevereiro, mimeo.
-
28
Estudos Econômicos739–765, A Computable General Equilibrium Model to Analyze Distributive Aspects in Brazil with a Trade Policy Illustration, Estudos Econômicos, São Paulo, IPE/FEA/USP, 35, 4.
-
29
‘The Impacts of Income Transfer Programs on Income Distribution and Poverty in Brazil: An Integrated Microsimulation and Computable General Equilibrium Analysis’. MPIA-PEP Working Paper 11086‘The Impacts of Income Transfer Programs on Income Distribution and Poverty in Brazil: An Integrated Microsimulation and Computable General Equilibrium Analysis’. MPIA-PEP Working Paper 11086.
- 30
-
31
‘Poverty Analysis within a General Equilibrium Framework’. Working Paper 99-09African Economic Research Consortium.
-
32
‘How to Measure Poverty and Inequality in General Equilibrium Framework’. Working Paper #9920Laval University, CREFA.
-
33
General Equilibrium Models for Development PolicyLondon: Cambridge University Press.
-
34
‘From stylized to applied models: building multisector CGE models for models for policy analysis’. CUDARE Working Paper Series‘From stylized to applied models: building multisector CGE models for models for policy analysis’. CUDARE Working Paper Series, nº. 616, University of California at Berkeley, Dept. of Agricultural and Resource Economics and Policy.
- 35
-
36
‘Evidence of eligibility manipulation for conditional cash transfer programs’EconomiA 15:243–260.
- 37
-
38
Handbook of Labor EconomicsHome Production – A Survey, Handbook of Labor Economics, 1, chapter 4, Amsterdan, North Holland.
-
39
Income Distribution and Growth: A Simulation Model for KenyaIn: DG Greene, editors. Kenya: Growth and Structural Change. Washington, DC: World Bank. pp. 487–621.
- 40
- 41
-
42
Parcerias Estratégicas - Edição especial: Análise sobre a Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de Domicílios (Pnad 2004)77–88, Brasil, 2004: Menos pobres e menos ricos, Parcerias Estratégicas - Edição especial: Análise sobre a Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de Domicílios (Pnad 2004), Brasília, Centro de Gestão e Estudos Estratégicos, 22.
-
43
‘Transferências de renda e a redução da desigualdade no Brasil e cinco regiões entre 1997 e 2004’Econômica. Rio de Janeiro 8:55–81.
-
44
Comunicados IPEAA Década Inclusiva (2001-2011): Desigualdade, Pobreza e Políticas de Renda, Comunicados IPEA, 155, Sept, 25, Brasília.
- 45
-
46
‘The welfare effects of balance of payments reforms: A macro-micro simulation of the cost of rent-seeking’The Journal of Development Studies 39:101–128.
-
47
‘Evaluating the economic effects of income security reforms in Switzerland: an integrated microsimulation - computable general equilibrium approach’. Working PaperUniversity of Geneva.
-
48
‘Inter-industry wage differentials and earnings inequality in Brazil’Estúdios de Economia 21:79–111.
-
49
‘Redução da Desigualdade Renda no Brasil: determinantes e consequências’ESAF - VI Prêmio SOF de Monografias.
-
50
CIRPRÉ – Centre Interuniversitaire sur le Risque, les Politiques Économiques et l’Emploi. Working Paper 03-4339, CIRPRÉ – Centre Interuniversitaire sur le Risque, les Politiques Économiques et l’Emploi. Working Paper 03-43.
-
51
‘Poverty and inequality analysis within a CGE Framework: a comparative analysis of the representative agent and microsimulation approaches’Development Policy Review 23:313–332.
-
52
Avaliando o Impacto do Programa Bolsa Família: uma Comparacão com Programas de TransferênciaC ondicionada de Renda de Outros Países. IPC Evaluation Note, No. 1Brasília: IPC.
-
53
XIII Seminário sobre Economia Mineira – Economia, História, Demografia e Políticas PúblicasEfeito do Programa Bolsa Família sobre a Oferta de Trabalho das Mães, XIII Seminário sobre Economia Mineira – Economia, História, Demografia e Políticas Públicas, Diamantina – MG – Brasil, agosto de.
-
54
‘Vanishing income redistributions: Keynesian clues about model surprises in the short-run’Journal of Development Economics 6:11–29.
-
55
‘Análise do Impacto do Programa Bolsa Família na Oferta de Trabalho dos Homens e Mulheres’UNDP/IPC, http://www.ipc-undp.org/publications/mds/27P.pdf.
-
56
‘Trade liberalization and poverty in Ecuador: a CGE macromicrosimulation analysis’Economic System Research 15:211–232.
Article and author information
Author details
Acknowledgements
This work was carried out with financial and scientific support from the Partnership for Economic Policy (PEP), with funding from the Department for International Development (DFID) of the United Kingdom (or UK Aid), and the Government of Canada through the International Development Research Center (IDRC).
Publication history
- Version of Record published: April 30, 2016 (version 1)
Copyright
© 2016, Cury
This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use and redistribution provided that the original author and source are credited.