A Brief Survey of Behavioral Modeling in Micro Simulation Models
Since the start of microsimulation in economics with Orcutt’s seminal 1957 article (Orcutt, 1957), and the first dynamic microsimulation model in the United States (Orcutt, 1961), this approach has in the past almost 40 years been both successful and met with a great degree of skepticism. Successful to the extent that static microsimulation models have become a standard tool for policy evaluation in most Western governments, but at the same time less accepted among academic economists, who sometimes find unacceptable the compromises between theoretical and methodological rigor and what is feasible given insufficient data and resources. They have not seen a microsimulation model as a useful tool in developing and testing theory.
Nonetheless, there is a rather impressive list of micro simulation models as shown by recent surveys, for instance, Merz (1991), Mot (1992), the OECD (1988) and Sutherland (1995), and by a number of conference volumes, for instance, Bergman et al. (1980), Orcutt et al. (1986) and Harding (1996). Many microsimulation models are static without behavioral relations, and this is in particular true for models run by government agencies, international organizations and consulting firms. Behavioral modeling is still to a large extent an academic exercise. Tables 1–3 list models which at least include some behavioral relation. These tables have been put together using primary as well as secondary sources, for instance the survey articles mentioned above, which implies that a few models could well have become misclassified. What defines a behavioral relation is not crystal clear. A matrix of transition probabilities differentiated by age and sex is a simple behavioral relation in the sense that behavior is differentiated by age and sex. Some models include relations derived from economic theory but this is not a requirement for a model to become classified as behavioral. For instance, demographic models of transition matrix type have been included. Although these models include behavioral heterogeneity in a broad sense many of them do not capture any behavioral response to policy changes. Their behavioral relations do not include the relevant policy parameters.
There is also another type of behavioral modeling applied to micro simulation models where behavior is modeled at an aggregate level. The aggregate implications are then subsequently disaggregated in a micro simulation model. An example is Meagher (1996). A dynamic general equilibrium model of the Australian economy is used to compute growth rates in the (factor) incomes of selected groups. These income changes are then fed into a static micro simulation model, which produces simulations of the after-tax income distribution. A similar application is also given in Baekgaard and Robinson (1997). In the following we will not pursue further the linkage with the macro economy.
Table 1 includes static MSM with behavioral relations. One may note that among the most common behavioral relations are those of labor supply but there are also models which include expenditure functions to simulate the effects and changes in indirect taxation. The early models were designed in the United States while the Europeans caught up in the 1980s and now seem to dominate the work with static behavioral models.
Table 2 lists general dynamic models with behavioral relations. “General” here means two things. The model is not specialized for a very limited purpose or limited to a small group of individuals or households, and it contains more than a single or just a few behavioral relations. Most of these models are large and cover the whole household sector in a country and include modules which age their populations as well as modules which are more central to the general purpose of the models, for instance, labor supply relations which capture behavioral adjustments in the labor market to tax changes. The behavioral relations of all models, however, are not specified such that behavior directly depends on the policy instruments, some are more of a demographic type. Also, in dynamic modeling the Americans were pioneers. In Europe German scientists would seem to have worked relatively early with dynamic microsimulation models.
Table 3 shows microsimulation models with a more specialized aim and limited scope. Labor market behavior is dominating among these models as well, but here is a greater variety of coverage: consumption behavior, housing demand, demand for energy, childcare, telephone services and non-market time. Most of these models are probably more closely based on economic models and econometric testing and estimation than the big general dynamic models.
1. Behavioral modeling for three purposes
A Behavioral model can serve at least three purposes in a microsimulation model. First it could be used to impute missing data as an alternative to statistical matching (see Klevmarken, 1983).1 Suppose there are X1 data in the data set used for simulation, but X2 data are missing, and that there is another data set with both X1 and X2 data. If X2 can be related to X1 by way of a behavioral model then the model can be estimated from the second, external data set and used in the micro simulation model to simulate X2. Such a relation need not be based on theory about behavior, what is needed is a good predictive relation, but if it is delivered from good theory, one would probably have more confidence in its predictive ability.
Behavioral models can also be used to age the simulation population (sample). This is usually done by introducing mortality tables, relations for the birth of new individuals, marriages, separations etc. Similarly, behavioral relations could update other characteristics of the population like the labor force participation, unemployment, hours of work, wage rates, housing, childcare etc. As long as the purpose is limited to updating, behavioral relations are only needed to the extent that they yield more stable and precise predictive relations compared to alternative ways of updating the population. In practice many models use matrices of transition probabilities estimated separately for a few subgroups of the population, for instance, by age and sex, but with no strong connection to theory.
The third and perhaps most interesting application of behavioral relations is to capture behavioral adjustments to policy changes. A necessary requirement of a behavioral model to satisfy this purpose is that the policy parameters directly or indirectly enter the model. This is normally not the case in the simple transition matrixes used for aging and updating. For instance, in a study of the distributional effects of income tax changes the labor supply function should be such that labor supply depends on the tax rates (and virtual income). A second requirement is that the behavioral relation is stable such that its parameters do not change as a result of policy changes. This is an issue much discussed, for instance, in relation to the recent major tax reforms in many countries. Can labor supply relations estimated on data collected before the reforms be used to predict or evaluate the effects of the reforms? Are the parameter estimates stable in spite of the large tax changes in some countries? The same kind of concern could be raised when microsimulation models are used to simulate processes of long duration, for instance changes in pension systems. Is it possible to extrapolate long into the future earnings and labor supply relations estimated from short time spans of data?
2. Behavioral modeling in static micro simulation models
To emphasize the policy evaluation application of micro simulation models and make behavioral adjustments explicit assume there are three kinds of variables: Policy variables Xp, target variables Y and all other variables Xnp. For instance, one could think of Xp as tax rates and tax bases, Y as taxes paid and after tax income, while Xnp would include variables needed to compute taxes like labor incomes and nonlabor incomes, and group indices like sex, marital status, nationality, region, etc. In a conventional nonbehavioral static tax-benefit model policy variables are related to the target variables through the tax and benefit system conditional on Xnp. For a single individual we could write this relation as,
In a microsimulation application of this model we compare the distributions of
and
for two different policy regimes Xp1 and Xp2 and a given set of population characteristics Xnp 0.
Replicated static microsimulation actually approximates the distribution,
from which we can compute the marginal distributions by simple summation,
and
and various distributions conditional on subsets of Xnp0, for instance on gender, type of family, region, etc. It is here assumed that the empirical distribution of Xnp0 in the microsimulation model closely approximates the true distribution of Xnp0, which for instance would be the case if the sample used for micro simulation is a simple random sample from the target population. (If the sample is drawn with unequal sampling probabilities one would have to compensate for this by using appropriate sampling weights.)
If the model T(..) is just a nonstochastic tax-benefit model the distribution (5) could be a degenerate one-point distribution. It is of course still possible to compute the marginal distributions (6a) and (6b) and various conditional distributions. If T(..) is a stochastic model and the simulation is only done once we might not get a good approximation of the distribution (5), depending on how frequently Xnp0 is replicated in the simulated population. The reason is of course that we will only get one observation (Y1, Y2) for each individual. However, we can still compute good approximations of the marginal distributions (6a) and (6b) and various interesting conditional distributions.
The marginal distribution f(Y1, Y2| Xp1, Xp2) is of particular interest, because it tells us, for instance, about the after tax income mobility. What share of the population move from one after tax income decile to another as a result of the change in policy? Although Xnp0 has been integrated out f(Y1, Y2| Xp1, Xp2) is only valid for a population with the characteristics Xnp0. Please also note that nothing is said and nothing can be said about the individual trajectories through time which result from a policy change. Nor do we say anything about changes through time in the distribution of Y or when a certain share of the population has moved from one decil to another.
Assume now that in addition to the tax-benefit model some of the variables Xnp also depend on the policy regime. To mark their changed status call them Yp , and keep the old notation Xnp for variables which are truly exogenous. A static model with behavioral adjustments could be written as,
Where C is a function which relates the policy variables to individual behavior of relevance for the target variables. One could, for instance think of C as a labor supply model which determines hours of work (Yp) as a function of the tax rates, deductions and thresholds (Xp) and wage rates and nonlabor incomes (Xnp). All these variables thus jointly determine disposable income.
Microsimulation of this model will, for instance, involve a comparison of the following two distributions,
and the corresponding pairs of marginal distributions,
and
Again, there is no time dimension in this model. Although it is possible to compute the distribution f(Y1, Y2, Yp1, Yp2 | Xp1, Xp2), which, for instance could tell us what share of the unemployed became employed as a result of the policy change, it does not tell us when. Depending on how the model is designed and estimated and the simulations done this distribution might also vastly overestimate mobility. If C(..) is a stochastic model such that the implicit individual random error is drawn independently for each policy regime then the model neglects any unobserved individual heterogeneity and it would simulate too much mobility. Although such a model could not be used to evaluate the “true” distribution f(Y1, Y2, Yp1, Yp2 | Xp1, Xp2) it might still simulate well the marginal distributions (8), (9) and (10).
Suppose, for instance, that C is a static labor supply model of the Hausman type and Yp is hours of work, and that this model is simulated for two different tax regimes. If the random “optimization errors” of the Hausman model are IID, and independent sets of errors are drawn for the two tax regimes, then mobility in hours will most certainly become exaggerated. This excess mobility will then transmit to disposable income. In this example the simulated joint distribution of disposable income and hours of work for the two policy regimes F(Y1, Y2, Yp1, Yp2| Xp1, Xp2) is the product of the marginal distributions f(Yt, Ypt| Xpt), t=1,2. Although this is believed to be unrealistic it does not exclude that each of the simulated marginal distributions are good approximations.
One way to reduce mobility is to use the same seed when the two sets of “optimizing errors” are drawn. Each individual will then have the same error in both tax regimes. However, there is no guarantee this approach will give a realistic representation of mobility. It might well create too little mobility. The simulation procedure should be based on empirical studies of mobility, and then a static model is not a good framework.
An alternative explanation to a smaller mobility compared to a purely random process is the presence of state dependence.2 Assume, for instance, that,
In this model behavior does not only depend on the policy Xp chosen and the exogenous characteristics Xnp, but also on a reference "level" of policy Xp0, target variables Y0 and behavioral response variables Yp0. For instance, the effect of a tax change on labor supply might depend on the level of unemployment when the tax change is implemented. It might also depend on the nature of the tax system used immediately before the tax change. The behavioral response to a change in the marginal tax rate may depend on whether the rate was higher or lower prior to the change.
3. Families of behavioral models
Only human imagination, data availability and computer resources limit the structures and forms behavioral models could take, and it is certainly possible to group existing models in many different ways. The following classification indicates the variety of approaches and functional forms used, many of which can usually be found within one and the same micro simulation model.
Models of transitions between different states: To this class belong models of transition probabilities like Markov-models, probit, logit, multinomial logit and ordered probit models to mention a few. It also includes event history (hazard rate) models.
Count data models: Count data models like for instance Poisson regression have been used to model the number of occurrences of an event in an a priori specified time span or the number of time periods an individual belongs to a certain state, for instance, the number of months of unemployment in a year or the number of weeks reported absent from work due to sickness in a year. These models have been used when event history data were not available, one only knew for how many weeks a person had been in a state, for instance sick, but not if these weeks formed one or more spells of sickness.
Continuous data models: To this group belong conventional linear and nonlinear regression models, equation systems etc. In micro simulation models for earnings functions, models for work hours and expenditure functions are examples of this model type.
Random assignment schemes (statistical matching): The models of the first three classes above belong to the conventional econometric paradigm of estimating an average structure from which there are only random deviations. In the first two cases one estimates (average) probabilities conditional on certain individual characteristics and the deviation from the most probable outcome is accomplished by chance, by throwing a ”loaded dice”. In the third case we simulate deviations from the average by adding random disturbances to the ”systematic” part of the model. In random assignment schemes like statistical matching, the model structure is implied and never estimated. It is only defined by the variables which define ”closeness”. The idea is to find a donor of data among the observations in the population which in some sense is similar or close to the receiving unit. Suppose for instance, that the original data set includes observations on income for two consecutive years for each individual. A simulated income distribution for a third year could be obtained by defining closeness between the donor’s income in the first year and the receiver’s income in the second year perhaps also between other variables like age and sex and then randomly select a donor among those who have the (approximately) same age, sex and income as the receiver. The donor’s income for the second year is then used as a prediction of the receiver’s income in year three. The implicit model assumption is of course that income transitions remain unchanged. With a similar but somewhat more elaborate approach Hussenius and Selén (1994) linked short panels of income data to life-cycle income paths to analyze how like-cycle incomes were influenced by tax and transfer changes. In the MICROHUS model (Klevmarken et al., 1992; Klevmarken and Olovsson, 1996) the technique was used to simulate the properties of the house a family was predicted to buy (size, tax assessed value, size of mortgage and interest paid).
Advantages with the random assignment technique are thus that no assumptions of functional forms or distribution families are needed, if preserves the variation and (most of) the correlation already present in the original data, and it is nonparametric so there is no estimation of unknown parameters. The choice of variables and the measure used to define closeness can be tested by goodness of fit. A disadvantage though is that the statistical properties of the resulting ”predictions” are incompletely known. Results from the imputation literature might be relevant. Another practical disadvantage is that the random assignment technique can never predict beyond the range of values already present in the original sample.
With exception of the random assignment technique the more traditional approaches to modeling invites the model builder to become excessively parsimonious with the number of estimated parameters and the models thus tend to become of the type average behavior with random variation. The possibility to permit people to behave fundamentally differently and to study the interaction between people with different aims which is feasible within the micro simulation approach, is usually not taken advantage of. For instance, with panel data, only a few observations for each individual are needed to estimate a utility function for each individual and allow everyone to maximize her own utility. One could also think of models when some individuals maximize their utility while the behavior of others are guided by something else than utility maximization!
4. The time unit in dynamic models
Continuous time models have the attraction to accommodate any time span one might like to use and also to permit different time spans for different purposes and in different sub models. However, a continuous time model which would permit the complexity and interaction between individuals which is necessary in most micro simulation models would become exceedingly difficult to estimate and simulate. It is thus probably not practical to have the entire microsimulation model formulated in continuous time. Continuous time might, however, be useful in certain sub models.
In micro simulation models which include income tax systems it is necessary to use the time unit of a year because income taxes are usually assessed annually. Some benefit systems, however, operate on shorter time spans. For instance, compensation for sickness and unemployment and social assistance might be given on a daily, weekly or monthly basis for the duration of the particular state. There is thus a need to use more than one time unit within a micro simulation model. This could be accomplished in several ways. One approach is to run simulation loops within a year for those sub models which operate on a shorter time unit, another approach is to use count models which simulate the number of days, weeks or months a person is sick, unemployed, etc in a year. A third approach is to use a continuous time model, for instance an event history model, to simulate the date when a person enters and leaves a certain state. The last approach has the advantage that it can accommodate a particular problem which sometimes occurs, namely that benefit rules are changed such that the change takes effect at a date other than the 1st of January.
5. Conclusions
After the dismal experiences with structural macro models we had the hope that modeling at the micro level and using large samples of micro data would yield estimated relations with some stability and scope. This hope has only been met to a limited extent (see for instance the discussion of models to capture work incentives in Atkinson and Mogensen, 1993). It is hard to know if this is the result of the nonexistence of stable micro relations, that the behavior of economic agents changes as the result of new policies, new institutions and other external changes, or of insufficient data and inadequate research approaches in economics (for a discussion see Klevmarken, 1994), or that the research process simply has to take more time. Behavioral modeling in the micro simulation context cannot be expected to go much beyond the state of art in economics. In each module of a large microsimulation model modeling meets with the same difficulties as in more conventional economic modeling, but in addition it has the difficulty of making the different modules fit together. There are obvious problems when modules have to be tested and estimated on different data sets, but there is also a requirement of an internal consistency of the model structure. For instance, if one module needs a particular explanatory variable, then another module is needed to simulate it such that the simulated values can be fed into the first module. To handle these problems the model builder needs a strategy as to the general model structure, as discussed above. A piecewise approach in which one starts with one module and then takes decisions about subsequent modules depending on the outcome of the research for the first is likely to lead to inconsistencies and to force the model builder to painful compromises for practical purposes.
It is also obvious that the availability of a rich data source of micro data will reduce the need to use supplementary data sets and thus greatly facilitate modeling. Depending on the purpose it would seem essential to have at least the key policy and effect variables included in the same data set. Assumptions of independence or conditional independence should be limited to relations which are of second order importance to the uses of the microsimulation model. If the dynamics of behavioral adjustments is important, which is almost always the case in policy simulations and evaluations, then panel data are needed. The large household panel data sets collected in several countries are thus essential for the construction of general microsimulation models of the household sector.
Modeling for regions larger than a country, EU for instance, would in principle require comparable data collected in all countries. Separate but comparable surveys in each country could be used to design comparable models for each country, which could be run one by one. Such an approach would make feasible an analysis of the same policy carried out in each country separately, but it would not permit the analysis of any interacting effects across boarders. If, for instance tax policies and social policies in one country are likely to attract or detract workers from another country, then a data collection design is needed which permits the survey people to follow respondents from one country to another to make feasible an analysis of the region wide policy effects mediated by migration.
Given that the above-mentioned difficulties can be handled in a satisfactory way microsimulation offers in principle opportunities to submit behavioral models to stronger tests than the usual diagnostic and specification testing done for each module separately. In addition to these tests a microsimulation model can be tested by comparing the simulated results with external data. Because simulated data can be aggregated, the data used to ”calibrate” against could either be micro data or aggregate data, for instance from the national accounts. It is a practical problem that these data need apply to the same population and observational units as the microsimulation model and they also need to comply with the same variable definitions.
The methodology for this ”calibration” is not fully developed. In particular there are a few issues which should be studied. First, the choice of criterion for a good model, second the inference theory needed to decide if the simulated (predicted) data lie within reasonable confidence bands from the observed data, and third, methods to evaluate the marginal influence of each parameter on the simulation results. It would be very useful to know which parameters have the most influence on the simulated results. A fourth issue is the estimation theory needed to incorporate new benchmark data.
Most of the modeling done in microsimulation is of the type ”average behavior with random deviations”. Conventional econometric models have been plugged into microsimulation models. As indicated above microsimulation offers opportunities to deviate from the paradigm of average behavior and allows for systematic differences in behavior, for instance, individual preference parameters estimated from panel data. One should probably also explore more the techniques to copy ”donors” by the random assignment approach, which avoids unnecessary restrictive assumptions about functional forms.
Footnotes
1.
A similar application is found in Birkin and Clarke (2006). They use proportional fitting in a micro-simulation approach to estimate small area income distributions.
2.
In empirical work it might not always be easy to distinguish state dependence from individual heterogeneity.
References
-
1
Demographic Forecasting with a Dynamic Stochastic Microsimulation Model. Discussion Paper Nr 85, Statistics NorwayDemographic Forecasting with a Dynamic Stochastic Microsimulation Model. Discussion Paper Nr 85, Statistics Norway.
-
2
”Framskrivning Av Arbeidsstyrke Og Utdanning. Mikrosimuleringsmodellen Mosart”, Rapporter 93/6, Statistics Norway”Framskrivning Av Arbeidsstyrke Og Utdanning. Mikrosimuleringsmodellen Mosart”, Rapporter 93/6, Statistics Norway.
-
3
The Future Burden of Public Pension Benefits. A Microsimulation Study. Discussion Papers No.115, Research Department, Statistics NorwayThe Future Burden of Public Pension Benefits. A Microsimulation Study. Discussion Papers No.115, Research Department, Statistics Norway.
-
4
Paper Prepared for the 1992 Conference on Computing for the Social Sciences at the University of Michigan, Ann ArborMosart - a microsimulation model, Paper Prepared for the 1992 Conference on Computing for the Social Sciences at the University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Statistics Norway, Oslo.
-
5
An Introduction to DYNAMOD: A dynamic Microsimulation ModelNATSEM, University of Canberra.
-
6
Telecommunications Demand Modelling An Integral ViewMicro-simulation of local residential telephone demand under alternative service options and rate structures, Telecommunications Demand Modelling An Integral View, Elsevier Publishers B.V.
- 7
-
8
IARIW Conference on Microsimulation and Public PolicyA Microsimulation approach to the Demand for Day Care for Children in Denmark, IARIW Conference on Microsimulation and Public Policy, Canberra, Australia.
-
9
5th Nordic Microsimulation SeminarThe distributional impact of microeconomic reform in Australia, 5th Nordic Microsimulation Seminar, Stockholm.
-
10
Paper for the IFS Conference Simulation of Tax ReformsSPEND- The IFS simulation program for energy demand, Paper for the IFS Conference Simulation of Tax Reforms.
- 11
-
12
Policy Analysis Series No.14Microsimulation as a policy tool: The math model, Policy Analysis Series No.14, Mathematica Policy Research Inc, Washington, DC.
-
13
A Microsimulation Model to Analyze Income Tax IndividualizationTilburg University Press.
-
14
Belasting- En Premieheffing En de Arbeidsparticipatie Door Gehuwde Vrouwen, Een Econometrische Analyse (Payment of Tax and Social Security Contributions and Labour Market Participation of Married Women, an Econometric AnalysisThe Hague: Ministry of Social Affairs and Employment.
-
15
Microanalytic Simulation Models to Support Social and Financial Policy83–97, Evaluating Reagan administration social program changes: Two applications of MATH, Microanalytic Simulation Models to Support Social and Financial Policy, North-Holland, Amsterdam, p.
-
16
Paper Voor de ECoZOEk-Day 28 April 1989Micropolis, Paper Voor de ECoZOEk-Day 28 April 1989, The Hague, Central Planning Office.
-
17
Micro-Simulation-Models, Methods and Applications, Industrial Institute for Economic and Social Research (IUI)Micro-Simulation-Models, Methods and Applications, Industrial Institute for Economic and Social Research (IUI), Stockholm.
-
18
Universal Versus Income-Tested ProgramsA simulation analysis of the economic efficiency and distribution effects of alternative program structures: The negative income tax versus the credit income tax, Universal Versus Income-Tested Programs, New York, Academic Press.
-
19
The Generation of Individual and Household Incomes at the Small Area Level using SynthesisRegional Studies 23:535–548.https://doi.org/10.1080/00343408912331345702
-
20
Studies of Income Distribution No.4, Social Security Administration, Office of Research and Statistics, US Department of Health, Education and WelfareEstimation of social security taxes on the March Current Population Survey, Studies of Income Distribution No.4, Social Security Administration, Office of Research and Statistics, US Department of Health, Education and Welfare, Washington, DC.
-
21
IBM Computing Conference, June 20, 1988Micro/macro simulation of socioeconomic population processes, IBM Computing Conference, June 20, 1988, Dallas.
-
22
IARIW Conference on Microsimulation and Public PolicyContent, validation and uses of CORSIM 2.0, a dynamic microanalytic model of the United States, IARIW Conference on Microsimulation and Public Policy, Canberra, Australia.
-
23
Tax Policy Toward Health Insurance and the Demand for Medical ServicesJournal of Health Economics 6:1–25.https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-6296(87)90028-2
-
24
Users Guide for ASTER, A Microsimulation Model for Indirect Taxes”, Centrum Voor Economische StudiënUsers Guide for ASTER, A Microsimulation Model for Indirect Taxes”, Centrum Voor Economische Studiën, K.U. Leuven.
-
25
MATH Technical Description, Mathematica Policy Research IncMATH Technical Description, Mathematica Policy Research Inc, Washington, DC.
-
26
University of Konstanz Discussion Paper, Series II No 153A Microsimulation model of labour supply for UK tax reform, University of Konstanz Discussion Paper, Series II No 153, Konstanz.
-
27
En Prognosmodell För Den Allmänna Tilläggspensioneringen, RiksförsäkringsverketEn Prognosmodell För Den Allmänna Tilläggspensioneringen, Riksförsäkringsverket, Stockholm.
-
28
Distributional Effects of Unemployment and Disinflation in Canada”, Unpublished Phd Thesis Dalhousie University, HalifaxDistributional Effects of Unemployment and Disinflation in Canada”, Unpublished Phd Thesis Dalhousie University, Halifax.
-
29
Winners and Losers from the Great Canadian Disinflation: 1981-1987. Working Paper No 92-13Economics Department, Dalhousie University, Halifax.
-
30
The Effect of Higher Unemployment on the distribution of Income in Canada: 1981-1987Canadian Public Policy / Analyse de Politiques 20:318.https://doi.org/10.2307/3551957
-
31
Welfare State Programme Research Note WSP/RN/24LIFEMOD - the Formative Years, Welfare State Programme Research Note WSP/RN/24, London School of Economics.
-
32
Microsimulation Models for Public Policy Analysis: New Frontiers, STICERED Occational Paper No 17, London School of EconomicsPlaying God: The Construction of LIFEMOD, a Dynamic Cohort Microsimulation Model, Microsimulation Models for Public Policy Analysis: New Frontiers, STICERED Occational Paper No 17, London School of Economics.
-
33
Behavioral Simulation Methods in Tax Policy AnalysisBehavioral Simulation Methods in Tax Policy Analysis, Chicago, 10.7208/chicago/9780226241753.001.0001.
-
34
Young People’s Household Formation Processes within a Local Housing Market (in Swedish), Geografiska Regionstudier No 33, Uppsala University (PhD ThesisYoung People’s Household Formation Processes within a Local Housing Market (in Swedish), Geografiska Regionstudier No 33, Uppsala University (PhD Thesis.
-
35
21st General Conference of the International Association for Research in Income and Wealth, Aug 20-26Policy evaluation by microsimulation - the Frankfurt model, 21st General Conference of the International Association for Research in Income and Wealth, Aug 20-26, Lahnstein.
-
36
Microanalytic Simulation Models to Support Social and Financial PolicyThe microsimulation model of the Sfb 3 for the analysis of economic and social policies, pp 227-247 in, Microanalytic Simulation Models to Support Social and Financial Policy, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
-
37
ESRC Research Centre for the Micro-Economic Analysis of Fiscal PolicyTaxben: The IFS microsimulation tax and benefit model”, Working paper series, NO.W95/19, The Institute for Fiscal Studies, ESRC Research Centre for the Micro-Economic Analysis of Fiscal Policy, London.
-
38
Individualisering van uitkeringsrechtenEconomische Statistische Berichten 16-10-1991 pp. 1032–1040.
-
39
Association Internationale Des Démographes De Langue Française (AIDELF)De qui dépendent les personnes âgées dependants? Morbidité, Mortalité: problemes de mesure, faccteures devolution, essai de prospective, Association Internationale Des Démographes De Langue Française (AIDELF).
-
40
Microanalytic Simulation Models to Support Social and Financial PolicyLongitudinal microsimulation of life income, Microanalytic Simulation Models to Support Social and Financial Policy, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
-
41
Discussion Paper WSP/48 The Welfare State Programme, Suntory-Toyota International Centre for Economics and Related DisciplinesDynamic microsimulation models: problems and prospects, Discussion Paper WSP/48 The Welfare State Programme, Suntory-Toyota International Centre for Economics and Related Disciplines, London, ST/ICERD, London School of Economics and Political Sciences.
-
42
Lifetime Income Distribution and Redistribution: Applications of a Microsimulation ModelLifetime Income Distribution and Redistribution: Applications of a Microsimulation Model, North Holland, Amsterdam.
-
43
Microsimulation and Public PolicyMicrosimulation and Public Policy, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
-
44
Gutachten Im Auftrag Der Transfer-Enquete-KommissionAuswirkungen öffentlicher Bildungsausgaben in der BRD auf die Einkomensverteilung der Ausbildungsgeneration, Gutachten Im Auftrag Der Transfer-Enquete-Kommission, Stuttgart, Kohlhammer.
-
45
Microsimulation for Urban and Regional Policy Analysis, European Research in Regional ScienceSimulating an entire nation, Microsimulation for Urban and Regional Policy Analysis, European Research in Regional Science, London, Pion Lmtd.
-
46
Rapport till ESO, Ministers of Finance DS 1994:135Skatter och socialförsäkringar över livscykeln - En simuleringsmodell, Rapport till ESO, Ministers of Finance DS 1994:135, Stockholm.
-
47
TAXBEN2: The New IFS Tax-Benefit Model. IFS Working Paper 90/5TAXBEN2: The New IFS Tax-Benefit Model. IFS Working Paper 90/5.
-
48
The Family and Earnings History ModelThe Dynamic Simulation of Income Model (DYNASIM), The Family and Earnings History Model, Vol, 1, Washington, D.C, The Urban Institute.
-
49
The Jobs and Benefits History ModelThe Dynamic Simulation of Income Model (DYNASIM), The Jobs and Benefits History Model, Vol, II, Washington, D.C, The Urban Institute.
-
50
OSA-Working Document W61Household labor supply in the Netherlands in the eighties and nineties, OSA-Working Document W61, The Hague.
-
51
Draft Technical Documentation, ICF IncorporatedThe ICF pension and retirement income simulation model (PRISM) with the ICF/Brookings long-term care financing model, Draft Technical Documentation, ICF Incorporated, Washington, D.C.
-
52
Microsimulation Techniques for Tax and Transfer AnalysisPRISM, Dynamic simulation of pension and retirement income, Microsimulation Techniques for Tax and Transfer Analysis, Urban Institute.
- 53
- 54
- 55
-
56
Research 1994 Annual Report and ProgramEconomic astrology or empirical science, Research 1994 Annual Report and Program, Uppsala, Dep. of Economics, Uppsala University.
-
57
International Symposium on Economic Modelling, August-20, 1992A Microsimulation Model for the Swedish Household Sector. A Progress Report, International Symposium on Economic Modelling, August-20, 1992, Gothenburg, Sweden.
-
58
Microsimulation and Public PolicyDirect and behavioral effects of income tax changes - simulations with the Swedish model MICROHUS, Microsimulation and Public Policy, Elsevier Science Publishers, Amsterdam.
-
59
Microanalytic Simulation Systems: Technical DocumentationWashington, DC: The Hendrickson Corporation.
-
60
Microsimulation in Public PolicyForecasting changes in the distribution of income: An applied general equilibrium approach. Chapt. 16 in, Microsimulation in Public Policy, Amsterdam, Elsevier Science Publishers.
-
61
Sfb3-Arbeitspapier No. 176, Sonderforschungsbereich 3, Mikroanalytische Grundlagen Der Gesellschaftspolitik, Frankfurt/M., MannheimDas statische Sfb 3 Mikrosimulationsmodell - Konzeption und Realisierung mit einem relationalen Databanksystem, Sfb3-Arbeitspapier No. 176, Sonderforschungsbereich 3, Mikroanalytische Grundlagen Der Gesellschaftspolitik, Frankfurt/M., Mannheim.
-
62
Das statische Sfb 3 Mikrosimulationsmodell - Konzeption und Realisierung mit einem relationalen DatenbanksystemAngewandte Informatik 5/86:205–212.
-
63
Habilitation ThesisMarkt- und nicht marktmässige Aktivitäten privater Haushalte - Theoretischer Ansatz, repräsentative Mikrodaten, Mikroökonometrische Analyse und Mikrosimation wirtschafts- und sozialpolitischer Massnahmen für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland, Habilitation Thesis, Univ. of Frankfurt.
-
64
Sfb 3-Working Paper No.307, Sonderforschungsbereich 3, Mikroanalytische Grundlagen Der Gesellschaftspolitik, Frankfurt/M., MannheimMarket and nonmarket labor supply and taxes - Multiple time allocation model microeconometric estimation and microsimulation of the German 1990 tax reform, Sfb 3-Working Paper No.307, Sonderforschungsbereich 3, Mikroanalytische Grundlagen Der Gesellschaftspolitik, Frankfurt/M., Mannheim.
-
65
Simulation Models in Tax and Transfer Policy, Campus,Frankfurt/MThe 1990 German tax reform - Microsimulation of time allocation effects in the formal and informal economy, Simulation Models in Tax and Transfer Policy, Campus,Frankfurt/M, New York.
-
66
Microsimulation - A survey of principles, developments and applicationsInternational Journal of Forecasting 7:77–104.https://doi.org/10.1016/0169-2070(91)90035-T
-
67
IARIW Conference on Microsimulation and Public Policy, Dec. 6-9Market and Non-market Labor Supply and Recent German Tax Reform Impacts, IARIW Conference on Microsimulation and Public Policy, Dec. 6-9, Canberra, Australia.
-
68
Sfb 3-Arbeitspapier Nr 316, Sonderforschungsbereich 3, Mikroanalytische Grundlagen Der Gesellschaftspolitik, Frankfurt/M., MannheimMICSIM: Ein PC-Mikrosimulationsmodell für Forschung und Lehre realisiert mit C und dem relationalen Datenbanksystem ORACLE, Sfb 3-Arbeitspapier Nr 316, Sonderforschungsbereich 3, Mikroanalytische Grundlagen Der Gesellschaftspolitik, Frankfurt/M., Mannheim.
-
69
Ministerie van Sociale Zahen en WerkgelegenheidSurvey of microsimulation models: inventory and recommendations, Ministerie van Sociale Zahen en Werkgelegenheid, S-Gravenhage.
-
70
Towards a Payable Pension System. Costs and Redistributive Impact of the Current Dutch Pension System and Three AlternativesThe Netherlands: TISSER, Tilburg Institute for Social Security Research/Department of Social Security Studies, Tilburg University, Tilburg.
-
71
OECD Studies in TaxationA comparative Study of Personal Income Tax Models, OECD Studies in Taxation, Paris.
-
72
A new type of socio-economic systemThe Review of Economics and Statistics 39:116.https://doi.org/10.2307/1928528
- 73
-
74
Microanalytic Simulation”, Working Paper 9/21/76, The Institution for Social and Policy StudiesNew Haven: Yale University.
-
75
Microanalytic Simulation Models to Support Social and Financial PolicyAmsterdam: North-Holland.
-
76
Towards A theory of wealth accumulation and distribution: A model of US household wealth accumulationAnnales de L’inséé, No 33-34 Pp pp. 5–57.https://doi.org/10.2307/20075320
-
77
Working DraftGuide to the HEW welfare simulation model, Working Draft, Washington D.C, Dep. of health, Education and Welfare.
-
78
Preferenze, Prezzireletivi e RedistribuzionePreferenze, Prezzireletivi e Redistribuzione, Bologna, IL Mulino.
-
79
The Microsimulation UnitPOLIMOD: An Outline, MU/RN5, The Microsimulation Unit, Dep. of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge.
-
80
Static Microsimulation Models in Europe: A Survey. DAE Working Paper No 9523University of Cambridge.
-
81
Microsimulation in Public PolicyModelling consumer behavioral response to commodity tax reforms in microsimulation models, Microsimulation in Public Policy, Elsevier Science Publishers, Amsterdam.
-
82
Minimum Wage Rate and Unemployment in the NetherlandsDe Economist 137:279–308.https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02115696
-
83
Towards a new generation of TRIM: Efficient data structure and supporting featuresWashington, DC: Urban Institute Working paper No.1281-02, The Urban Institute.
-
84
TRIM user’s guide”, Urban Institute Working paper No.1281-02Washington, DC: The Urban Institute.
-
85
Microanalytic Simulation Models to Support Social and Financial PolicyDynasim in comparison with other microsimulation models, pp 227-247 in, Microanalytic Simulation Models to Support Social and Financial Policy, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
-
86
Simulation Models in Tax and Transfer PolicyIncome tax / transfer integration - policy implications and analytical challenges, Simulation Models in Tax and Transfer Policy, Proceedings of an International Symposium. Campus Verlag, Frankfurt/New York.
-
87
Microsimulation Techniques for Tax and Transfer AnalysisThe development of the Dynamic Simulation of Income Model (DYNASIM), pp 109-136 in, Microsimulation Techniques for Tax and Transfer Analysis, Washington, D.C, The Urban Institute Press.
Article and author information
Author details
Funding
No specific funding for this article is reported.
Acknowledgements
This article has originally been published as Sections 3 and 5 in N. Anders Klevmarken (1997) Behavioral Modeling in Micro Simulation Models. A Survey, Working Paper 1997:31, Department of Economics, Uppsala University.
Publication history
- Version of Record published: April 30, 2022 (version 1)
Copyright
© 2022, Anders Klevmarken
This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use and redistribution provided that the original author and source are credited.